Friday, April 8, 2016

Bretton Woods

Bretton Woods system

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

The Bretton Woods system of monetary management established the rules for commercial and financial relations among the United StatesCanada,Western EuropeAustralia and Japan in the mid-20th century. The Bretton Woods system was the first example of a fully negotiated monetary order intended to govern monetary relations among independent nation-states. The chief features of the Bretton Woods system were an obligation for each country to adopt a monetary policy that maintained the exchange rate (± 1 per cent) by tying its currency to gold and the ability of the IMF to bridge temporary imbalances of payments. Also, there was a need to address the lack of cooperation among other countries and to prevent competitive devaluation of the currencies as well.
Preparing to rebuild the international economic system while World War II was still raging, 730 delegates from all 44 Allied nations gathered at the Mount Washington Hotel in Bretton Woods, New Hampshire, United States, for the United Nations Monetary and Financial Conference, also known as the Bretton Woods Conference. The delegates deliberated during 1–22 July 1944, and signed the Bretton Woods agreement on its final day. Setting up a system of rules, institutions, and procedures to regulate the international monetary system, these accords established the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and theInternational Bank for Reconstruction and Development (IBRD), which today is part of the World Bank Group. The United States, which controlled two thirds of the world's gold, insisted that the Bretton Woods system rest on both gold and the US dollarSoviet representatives attended the conference but later declined to ratify the final agreements, charging that the institutions they had created were "branches of Wall Street."[1] These organizations became operational in 1945 after a sufficient number of countries had ratified the agreement.
On 15 August 1971, the United States unilaterally terminated convertibility of the US dollar to gold, effectively bringing the Bretton Woods system to an end and rendering the dollar a fiat currency.[2] This action, referred to as the Nixon shock, created the situation in which the US dollar became a reserve currencyused by many states. At the same time, many fixed currencies (such as the pound sterling, for example) also became free-floating.

Origins[edit]

The political basis for the Bretton Woods system was in the confluence of two key conditions: the shared experiences of two World Wars, with the sense that failure to deal with economic problems after the first war had led to the second; and the concentration of power in a small number of states.

Interwar period[edit]

There was a high level of agreement among the powerful nations that failure to coordinate exchange rates during the interwar period had exacerbated political tensions. This facilitated the decisions reached by the Bretton Woods Conference. Furthermore, all the participating governments at Bretton Woods agreed that the monetary chaos of the interwar period had yielded several valuable lessons.
The experience of World War II was fresh in the minds of public officials. The planners at Bretton Woods hoped to avoid a repeat of the Treaty of Versaillesafter World War I, which had created enough economic and political tension to lead to WWII. After World War I, Britain owed the US substantial sums, which Britain could not repay because it had used the funds to support allies such as France during the War; the Allies could not pay back Britain, so Britain could not pay back the US. The solution at Versailles for the French, British, and Americans seemed to be "make Germany pay for it all." If the demands on Germany were unrealistic, then it was unrealistic for France to pay back Britain, and for Britain to pay back the US.[3] Thus, many "assets" on bank balance sheets internationally were actually unrecoverable loans, which culminated in the 1931 banking crisis. Intransigent insistence by creditor nations for the repayment of Allied war debts and reparations, combined with an inclination to isolationism, led to a breakdown of the international financial system and a worldwide economic depression.[4] The so-called "beggar thy neighbor" policies that emerged as the crisis continued saw some trading nations using currency devaluations in an attempt to increase their competitiveness (i.e. raise exports and lower imports), though recent research suggests this de facto inflationary policy probably offset some of the contractionary forces in world price levels(see Eichengreen "How to Prevent a Currency War").
In the 1920s, international flows of speculative financial capital increased, leading to extremes in balance of payments situations in various European countries and the US.[5] In the 1930s, world markets never broke through the haphazardly constructed, nationally motivated and imposed barriers and restrictions on international trade and investment volume. The various anarchic and often autarkic protectionist and neo-mercantilist national policies – often mutually inconsistent – that emerged over the first half of the decade worked inconsistently and self-defeatingly to promote national import substitution, increase national exports, divert foreign investment and trade flows, and even prevent certain categories of cross-border trade and investment outright. Global central bankers attempted to manage the situation by meeting with each other, but their understanding of the situation as well as difficulties in communicating internationally, hindered their abilities.[6] The lesson was that simply having responsible, hard-working central bankers was not enough.
Britain in the 1930s had an exclusionary trading bloc with nations of the British Empire known as the "Sterling Area." If Britain imported more than it exported to, say, South Africa, South African recipients of pounds sterling tended to put them into London banks. This meant that though Britain was running a trade deficit, it had a financial account surplus, and payments balanced. Increasingly, Britain's positive balance of payments required keeping the wealth of Empire nations in British banks. One incentive for, say, South African holders of rand to park their wealth in London and to keep the money in Sterling, was a strongly valued pound sterling. Unfortunately, as Britain deindustrialized in the 1920s, the way out of the trade deficit was to devalue the currency. But Britain couldn't devalue, or the Empire surplus would leave its banking system.[7]
Nazi Germany also worked with a bloc of controlled nations by 1940. Germany forced trading partners with a surplus to spend that surplus importing products from Germany.[8] Thus, Britain survived by keeping Sterling nation surpluses in its banking system, and Germany survived by forcing trading partners to purchase its own products. The US was concerned about a sudden drop-off in war spending which might return the nation to unemployment levels of the 1930s, and so wanted Sterling nations and everyone in Europe to be able to import from the US, hence the US supported free trade and international convertibility of currencies into gold or dollars.[9]

Post war negotiations[edit]

When many of these same expert observers reared on the 1930s debacle became the architects of a new, unified, post-war system at Bretton Woods, their guiding principles became "no more beggar thy neighbor" and "control flows of speculative financial capital." Preventing a repetition of this process of competitive devaluations was desired, but in a way that would not force debtor nations to contract their industrial bases by keeping interest rates at a level high enough to attract foreign bank deposits. John Maynard Keynes, wary of repeating the Great Depression, was behind Britain's proposal that surplus nations be forced by a "use-it-or-lose-it" mechanism, to either import from debtor nations, build factories in debtor nations or donate to debtor nations.[10][11]The US opposed Keynes' plan, and a senior official at the US Treasury, Harry Dexter White, rejected Keynes' proposals, in favor of an International Monetary Fund which would have enough resources to counteract destabilizing flows of speculative finance.[12] However, unlike the modern IMF, White's proposed fund would have counteracted dangerous speculative flows automatically, with no political strings attached—i.e., no IMF conditionality.[13] According to economic historian Brad Delong, on almost every point where he was overruled by the Americans, Keynes was later proved correct by events.[14]
Today these key 1930s events look different to scholars of the era (see the work of Barry Eichengreen Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919–1939 and How to Prevent a Currency War); in particular, devaluations today are viewed with more nuance. Ben Bernanke's opinion on the subject follows:
... [T]he proximate cause of the world depression was a structurally flawed and poorly managed international gold standard. ... For a variety of reasons, including a desire of the Federal Reserve to curb the US stock market boom, monetary policy in several major countries turned contractionary in the late 1920s—a contraction that was transmitted worldwide by the gold standard. What was initially a mild deflationary process began to snowball when the banking and currency crises of 1931 instigated an international "scramble for gold." Sterilization of gold inflows by surplus countries [the USA and France], substitution of gold for foreign exchange reserves, and runs on commercial banks all led to increases in the gold backing of money, and consequently to sharp unintended declines in national money supplies. Monetary contractions in turn were strongly associated with falling prices, output and employment. Effective international cooperation could in principle have permitted a worldwide monetary expansion despite gold standard constraints, but disputes over World War I reparations and war debts, and the insularity and inexperience of the Federal Reserve, among other factors, prevented this outcome. As a result, individual countries were able to escape the deflationary vortex only by unilaterally abandoning the gold standard and re-establishing domestic monetary stability, a process that dragged on in a halting and uncoordinated manner until France and the other Gold Bloc countries finally left gold in 1936. —Great Depression, B. Bernanke
In 1944 at Bretton Woods, as a result of the collective conventional wisdom of the time[citation needed], representatives from all the leading allied nations collectively favored a regulated system of fixed exchange rates, indirectly disciplined by a US dollar tied to gold[citation needed],—a system that relied on a regulated market economy with tight controls on the values of currencies. Flows of speculative international finance were curtailed by shunting them through and limiting them via central banks. This meant that international flows of investment went into foreign direct investment (FDI)—i.e., construction of factories overseas, rather than international currency manipulation or bond markets. Although the national experts disagreed to some degree on the specific implementation of this system, all agreed on the need for tight controls.

Economic security[edit]


Cordell Hull, US Secretary of State 1933–44
Also based on experience of the inter-war years, U.S. planners developed a concept of economic security—that a liberal international economic system would enhance the possibilities of postwar peace. One of those who saw such a security link was Cordell Hull, the United States Secretary of State from 1933 to 1944.[Notes 1] Hull believed that the fundamental causes of the two world wars lay in economic discrimination and trade warfare. Specifically, he had in mind the trade and exchange controls (bilateral arrangements)[15] of Nazi Germany and the imperial preference system practiced by Britain, by which members or former members of the British Empire were accorded special trade status, itself provoked by German, French, and American protectionist policies. Hull argued
[U]nhampered trade dovetailed with peace; high tariffs, trade barriers, and unfair economic competition, with war … if we could get a freer flow of trade…freer in the sense of fewer discriminations and obstructions…so that one country would not be deadly jealous of another and the living standards of all countries might rise, thereby eliminating the economic dissatisfaction that breeds war, we might have a reasonable chance of lasting peace.[16]

Rise of governmental intervention[edit]

The developed countries also agreed that the liberal international economic system required governmental intervention. In the aftermath of the Great Depression, public management of the economy had emerged as a primary activity of governments in the developed states.[citation needed] Employment, stability, and growth were now important subjects of public policy.
In turn, the role of government in the national economy had become associated with the assumption by the state of the responsibility for assuring its citizens of a degree of economic well-being.[citation needed] The system of economic protection for at-risk citizens sometimes called the welfare state grew out of theGreat Depression, which created a popular demand for governmental intervention in the economy, and out of the theoretical contributions of the Keynesianschool of economics, which asserted the need for governmental intervention to counter market imperfections.[citation needed]
However, increased government intervention in domestic economy brought with it isolationist sentiment that had a profoundly negative effect on international economics.[citation needed] The priority of national goals, independent national action in the interwar period, and the failure to perceive that those national goals could not be realized without some form of international collaboration—all resulted in "beggar-thy-neighbor" policies such as high tariffs, competitive devaluations that contributed to the breakdown of the gold-based international monetary system, domestic political instability, and international war. The lesson learned was, as the principal architect of the Bretton Woods system New Dealer Harry Dexter White put it:
the absence of a high degree of economic collaboration among the leading nations will … inevitably result in economic warfare that will be but the prelude and instigator of military warfare on an even vaster scale.
— [Notes 2]
To ensure economic stability and political peace, states agreed to cooperate to closely regulate the production of their currencies to maintain fixed exchange rates between countries with the aim of more easily facilitating international trade.[citation needed] This was the foundation of the U.S. vision of postwar worldfree trade, which also involved lowering tariffs and, among other things, maintaining a balance of trade via fixed exchange rates that would be favorable to the capitalist system.[citation needed]
Thus, the more developed market economies agreed with the U.S. vision of post-war international economic management, which was to be designed to create and maintain an effective international monetary system and foster the reduction of barriers to trade and capital flows.[citation needed] In a sense, the new international monetary system was in fact a return to a system similar to the pre-war gold standard, only using US dollars as the world's new reserve currency until the world's gold supply could be reallocated via international trade.[citation needed]
Thus, the new system would be devoid (initially) of governments meddling with their currency supply as they had during the years of economic turmoil preceding WWII. Instead, governments would closely police the production of their currencies and ensure that they would not artificially manipulate their price levels.[citation needed] If anything, Bretton Woods was a return to a time devoid of increased governmental intervention in economies and currency systems.[citation needed]

Atlantic Charter[edit]


Roosevelt and Churchill during their secret meeting of 9–12 August 1941, inNewfoundland resulted in the Atlantic Charter, which the U.S. and Britain officially announced two days later.
The Atlantic Charter, drafted during U.S. President Franklin D. Roosevelt's August 1941 meeting with British Prime Minister Winston Churchill on a ship in the North Atlantic, was the most notable precursor to the Bretton Woods Conference. Like Woodrow Wilson before him, whose "Fourteen Points" had outlined U.S. aims in the aftermath of theFirst World War, Roosevelt set forth a range of ambitious goals for the postwar world even before the U.S. had entered the Second World War.
The Atlantic Charter affirmed the right of all nations to equal access to trade and raw materials. Moreover, the charter called for freedom of the seas (a principal U.S. foreign policy aim since France and Britain had first threatened U.S. shipping in the 1790s), the disarmament of aggressors, and the "establishment of a wider and more permanent system of general security."
As the war drew to a close, the Bretton Woods conference was the culmination of some two and a half years of planning for postwar reconstruction by the Treasuries of the U.S. and the UK. U.S. representatives studied with their British counterparts the reconstitution of what had been lacking between the two world wars: a system of international payments that would allow trade to be conducted without fear of sudden currency depreciation or wild fluctuations in exchange rates — ailments that had nearly paralyzed world capitalism during the Great Depression.
Without a strong European market for U.S. goods and services, most policymakers believed, the U.S. economy would be unable to sustain the prosperity it had achieved during the war.[citation needed] In addition, U.S. unions had only grudgingly accepted government-imposed restraints on their demands during the war, but they were willing to wait no longer, particularly as inflation cut into the existing wage scales with painful force. (By the end of 1945, there had already been major strikes in the automobile, electrical, and steel industries.)[citation needed]
In early 1945 Bernard Baruch described the spirit of Bretton Woods as: if we can "stop subsidization of labor and sweated competition in the export markets,"as well as prevent rebuilding of war machines, "oh boy, oh boy, what long term prosperity we will have."[17] The United States [c]ould therefore use its position of influence to reopen and control the [rules of the] world economy, so as to give unhindered access to all nations' markets and materials.

Wartime devastation of Europe and East Asia[edit]

United States allies—economically exhausted by the war—needed U.S. assistance to rebuild their domestic production and to finance their international trade; indeed, they needed it to survive.[9]
Before the war, the French and the British realized that they could no longer compete with U.S. industries in an open marketplace.[citation needed] During the 1930s, the British created their own economic bloc to shut out U.S. goods. Churchill did not believe that he could surrender that protection after the war, so he watered down the Atlantic Charter's "free access" clause before agreeing to it.[citation needed]
Yet U.S. officials were determined to open their access to the British empire. The combined value of British and U.S. trade was well over half of all the world's trade in goods. For the U.S. to open global markets, it first had to split the British (trade) empire. While Britain had economically dominated the 19th century, U.S. officials intended the second half of the 20th to be under U.S. hegemony.[18]
A Senior Official of the Bank of England commented:
One of the reasons Bretton Woods worked was that the US was clearly the most powerful country at the table and so ultimately was able to impose its will on the others, including an often-dismayed Britain. At the time, one senior official at the Bank of England described the deal reached at Bretton Woods as "the greatest blow to Britain next to the war", largely because it underlined the way in which financial power had moved from the UK to the US.
— [19]
A devastated Britain had little choice. Two world wars had destroyed the country's principal industries that paid for the importation of half of the nation's food and nearly all its raw materials except coal. The British had no choice but to ask for aid. Not until the United States signed an agreement on 6 December 1945 to grant Britain aid of $4.4 billion did the British Parliament ratify the Bretton Woods Agreements (which occurred later in December 1945).[20]
For nearly two centuries, French and U.S. interests had clashed in both the Old World and the New World.[citation needed] During the war, French mistrust of the United States was embodied by General Charles de Gaulle, president of the French provisional government.[citation needed] De Gaulle bitterly fought U.S. officials as he tried to maintain his country's colonies and diplomatic freedom of action. In turn, U.S. officials saw de Gaulle as a political extremist.[citation needed]
But in 1945 de Gaulle—the leading voice of French nationalism—was forced to grudgingly ask the U.S. for a billion-dollar loan.[citation needed] Most of the request was granted; in return France promised to curtail government subsidies and currency manipulation that had given its exporters advantages in the world market.[citation needed]

Design of the financial system[edit]


The new 
economic system required an accepted vehicle for investment, trade, and payments. Unlike national economies, however, the international economy lacks a central government that can issue currency and manage its use. In the past this problem had been solved through the gold standard, but the architects of Bretton Woods did not consider this option feasible for the postwar political economy. Instead, they set up a system of fixed exchange ratesmanaged by a series of newly created international institutions using the U.S. dollar (which was a gold standard currency for central banks) as a reserve currency.Free trade relied on the free convertibility of currencies. Negotiators at the Bretton Woods conference, fresh from what they perceived as a disastrous experience with floating rates in the 1930s, concluded that major monetary fluctuations could stall the free flow of trade.

Informal regimes[edit]

Previous regimes[edit]

In the 19th and early 20th centuries gold played a key role in international monetary transactions. The gold standard was used to back currencies; the international value of currency was determined by its fixed relationship to gold; gold was used to settle international accounts. The gold standard maintained fixed exchange rates that were seen as desirable because they reduced the risk when trading with other countries.
Imbalances in international trade were theoretically rectified automatically by the gold standard. A country with a deficit would have depleted gold reserves and would thus have to reduce its money supply. The resulting fall in demand would reduce imports and the lowering of prices would boost exports; thus the deficit would be rectified. Any country experiencing inflation would lose gold and therefore would have a decrease in the amount of money available to spend.
This decrease in the amount of money would act to reduce the inflationary pressure. Supplementing the use of gold in this period was the British pound. Based on the dominant British economy, the pound became a reserve, transaction, and intervention currency. But the pound was not up to the challenge of serving as the primary world currency, given the weakness of the British economy after the Second World War.
The architects of Bretton Woods had conceived of a system wherein exchange rate stability was a prime goal. Yet, in an era of more activist economic policy, governments did not seriously consider permanently fixed rates on the model of the classical gold standard of the 19th century. Gold production was not even sufficient to meet the demands of growing international trade and investment. Further, a sizable share of the world's known gold reserves were located in theSoviet Union, which would later emerge as a Cold War rival to the United States and Western Europe.
The only currency strong enough to meet the rising demands for international currency transactions was the U.S. dollar. The strength of the U.S. economy, the fixed relationship of the dollar to gold ($35 an ounce), and the commitment of the U.S. government to convert dollars into gold at that price made the dollar as good as gold. In fact, the dollar was even better than gold: it earned interest and it was more flexible than gold.

Fixed exchange rates[edit]

The rules of Bretton Woods, set forth in the articles of agreement of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (IBRD), provided for a system of fixed exchange rates. The rules further sought to encourage an open system by committing members to the convertibility of their respective currencies into other currencies and to free trade.
What emerged was the "pegged rate" currency regime. Members were required to establish a parity of their national currencies in terms of the reserve currency (a "peg") and to maintain exchange rates within plus or minus 1% of parity (a "band") by intervening in their foreign exchange markets (that is, buying or selling foreign money).
In theory, the reserve currency would be the bancor (a World Currency Unit that was never implemented), suggested by John Maynard Keynes; however, the United States objected and their request was granted, making the "reserve currency" the U.S. dollar. This meant that other countries would peg their currencies to the U.S. dollar, and—once convertibility was restored—would buy and sell U.S. dollars to keep market exchange rates within plus or minus 1% of parity. Thus, the U.S. dollar took over the role that gold had played under the gold standard in the international financial system.[21]
Meanwhile, to bolster confidence in the dollar, the U.S. agreed separately to link the dollar to gold at the rate of $35 per ounce of gold. At this rate, foreign governments and central banks were able to exchange dollars for gold. Bretton Woods established a system of payments based on the dollar, in which all currencies were defined in relation to the dollar, itself convertible into gold, and above all, "as good as gold". The U.S. currency was now effectively the world currency, the standard to which every other currency was pegged. As the world's key currency, most international transactions were denominated in US dollars.[citation needed]
The U.S. dollar was the currency with the most purchasing power and it was the only currency that was backed by gold. Additionally, all European nations that had been involved in World War II were highly in debt and transferred large amounts of gold into the United States, a fact that contributed to the supremacy of the United States[citation needed]. Thus, the U.S. dollar was strongly appreciated in the rest of the world and therefore became the key currency of the Bretton Woods system.
Member countries could only change their par value by more than 10% with IMF approval, which was contingent on IMF determination that its balance of payments was in a "fundamental disequilibrium". The formal definition of fundamental disequilibrium was never determined, leading to uncertainty of approvals and attempts to repeatedly devalue by less than 10% instead.[22] Any country that changed without approval or after being denied was then denied access to the IMF.

Formal regimes[edit]

The Bretton Woods Conference led to the establishment of the IMF and the IBRD (now the World Bank), which still remain powerful forces in the world economy.
A major point of common ground at the Conference was the goal to avoid a recurrence of the closed markets and economic warfare that had characterized the 1930s. Thus, negotiators at Bretton Woods also agreed that there was a need for an institutional forum for international cooperation on monetary matters. Already in 1944 the British economist John Maynard Keynes emphasized "the importance of rule-based regimes to stabilize business expectations"—something he accepted in the Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates. Currency troubles in the interwar years, it was felt, had been greatly exacerbated by the absence of any established procedure or machinery for intergovernmental consultation.
As a result of the establishment of agreed upon structures and rules of international economic interaction, conflict over economic issues was minimized, and the significance of the economic aspect of international relations seemed to recede.

International Monetary Fund[edit]

Officially established on 27 December 1945, when the 29 participating countries at the conference of Bretton Woods signed its Articles of Agreement, the IMF was to be the keeper of the rules and the main instrument of public international management. The Fund commenced its financial operations on 1 March 1947. IMF approval was necessary for any change in exchange rates in excess of 10%. It advised countries on policies affecting the monetary system and lent reserve currencies to nations that had incurred balance of payment debts.
Design[edit]
The big question at the Bretton Woods conference with respect to the institution that would emerge as the IMF was the issue of future access to internationalliquidity and whether that source should be akin to a world central bank able to create new reserves at will or a more limited borrowing mechanism.

John Maynard Keynes (right) andHarry Dexter White at the inaugural meeting of the International Monetary Fund's Board of Governors in Savannah, Georgia, U.S., 8 March 1946
Although attended by 44 nations, discussions at the conference were dominated by two rival plans developed by the United States and Britain. As the chief international economist at the U.S. Treasury in 1942–44, Harry Dexter White drafted the U.S. blueprint for international access to liquidity, which competed with the plan drafted for the British Treasury by Keynes. Overall, White's scheme tended to favor incentives designed to create price stability within the world's economies, while Keynes' wanted a system that encouraged economic growth. The "collective agreement was an enormous international undertaking" that took two years prior of the conference to prepare for – it consisted of numerous bilateral and multilateral meetings to reach common ground on what policies would make up the Bretton Woods system.
At the time, gaps between the White and Keynes plans seemed enormous. White basically wanted a fund to reverse destabilizing flows of financial capital automatically. White proposed a new monetary institution called the Stabilization Fund that "would be funded with a finite pool of national currencies and gold… that would effectively limit the supply of reserve credit". Keynes wanted incentives for the US to help Britain and the rest of Europe rebuild after WWII.[23]Between the lines, Keynes' thought that world better off with the elite of the British empire running it, while White sympathized with the global working class freeing itself from Britain's empire[8] Outlining the difficulty of creating a system that every nation could accept in his speech at the closing plenary session of the Bretton Woods conference on 22 July 1944, Keynes stated:
We, the delegates of this Conference, Mr. President, have been trying to accomplish something very difficult to accomplish.[...] It has been our task to find a common measure, a common standard, a common rule acceptable to each and not irksome to any.
— [Notes 3]
Keynes' proposals would have established a world reserve currency (which he thought might be called "bancor") administered by a central bank vested with the possibility of creating money and with the authority to take actions on a much larger scale.
In case of balance of payments imbalances, Keynes recommended that both debtors and creditors should change their policies. As outlined by Keynes, countries with payment surpluses should increase their imports from the deficit countries, build factories in debtor nations, or donate to them—and thereby create a foreign trade equilibrium.[24] Thus, Keynes was sensitive to the problem that placing too much of the burden on the deficit country would be deflationary.
But the United States, as a likely creditor nation, and eager to take on the role of the world's economic powerhouse, used White's plan but targeted many of Keynes's concerns. White saw a role for global intervention in an imbalance only when it was caused by currency speculation.
Although compromise was reached on some points, because of the overwhelming economic and military power of the United States the participants at Bretton Woods largely agreed on White's plan.
Subscriptions and quotas[edit]
What emerged largely reflected U.S. preferences: a system of subscriptions and quotas embedded in the IMF, which itself was to be no more than a fixed pool of national currencies and gold subscribed by each country as opposed to a world central bank capable of creating money. The Fund was charged with managing various nations' trade deficits so that they would not produce currency devaluations that would trigger a decline in imports.
The IMF is provided with a fund, composed of contributions of member countries in gold and their own currencies. The original quotas were to total $8.8 billion. When joining the IMF, members are assigned "quotas" reflecting their relative economic power, and, as a sort of credit deposit, are obliged to pay a "subscription" of an amount commensurate with the quota. The subscription is to be paid 25% in gold or currency convertible into gold (effectively the dollar, which was the only currency then still directly gold convertible for central banks) and 75% in the member's own currency.
Quota subscriptions are to form the largest source of money at the IMF's disposal. The IMF set out to use this money to grant loans to member countries with financial difficulties. Each member is then entitled to withdraw 25% of its quota immediately in case of payment problems. If this sum should be insufficient, each nation in the system is also able to request loans for foreign currency.
Trade deficits[edit]
In the event of a deficit in the current account, Fund members, when short of reserves, would be able to borrow foreign currency in amounts determined by the size of its quota. In other words, the higher the country's contribution was, the higher the sum of money it could borrow from the IMF.
Members were required to pay back debts within a period of 18 months to five years. In turn, the IMF embarked on setting up rules and procedures to keep a country from going too deeply into debt year after year. The Fund would exercise "surveillance" over other economies for the U.S. Treasury in return for its loans to prop up national currencies.
IMF loans were not comparable to loans issued by a conventional credit institution. Instead, they were effectively a chance to purchase a foreign currency with gold or the member's national currency.
The U.S.-backed IMF plan sought to end restrictions on the transfer of goods and services from one country to another, eliminate currency blocs, and lift currency exchange controls.
The IMF was designed to advance credits to countries with balance of payments deficits. Short-run balance of payment difficulties would be overcome by IMF loans, which would facilitate stable currency exchange rates. This flexibility meant a member state would not have to induce a depression to cut its national income down to such a low level that its imports would finally fall within its means. Thus, countries were to be spared the need to resort to the classical medicine of deflating themselves into drastic unemployment when faced with chronic balance of payments deficits. Before the Second World War, European nations—particularly Britain—often resorted to this.
Par value[edit]
The IMF sought to provide for occasional discontinuous exchange-rate adjustments (changing a member's par value) by international agreement. Member nations were permitted to adjust their currency exchange rate by 1%. This tended to restore equilibrium in their trade by expanding their exports and contracting imports. This would be allowed only if there was a fundamental disequilibrium. A decrease in the value of a country's money was called a devaluation, while an increase in the value of the country's money was called a revaluation.
It was envisioned that these changes in exchange rates would be quite rare. However, the concept of fundamental disequilibrium, though key to the operation of the par value system, was never defined in detail.
Operations[edit]
Never before had international monetary cooperation been attempted on a permanent institutional basis. Even more groundbreaking was the decision to allocate voting rights among governments, not on a one-state one-vote basis, but rather in proportion to quotas. Since the United States was contributing the most, U.S. leadership was the key. Under the system of weighted voting, the United States exerted a preponderant influence on the IMF. The United States held one-third of all IMF quotas at the outset, enough on its own to veto all changes to the IMF Charter.
In addition, the IMF was based in Washington, D.C., and staffed mainly by U.S. economists. It regularly exchanged personnel with the U.S. Treasury. When the IMF began operations in 1946, President Harry S. Truman named White as its first U.S. Executive Director. Since no Deputy Managing Director post had yet been created, White served occasionally as Acting Managing Director and generally played a highly influential role during the IMF's first year.

International Bank for Reconstruction and Development[edit]

The agreement made no provisions for international creation of reserves. New gold production was assumed to be sufficient. In the event of structural disequilibria, it was expected that there would be national solutions, for example, an adjustment in the value of the currency or an improvement by other means of a country's competitive position. The IMF was left with few means, however, to encourage such national solutions.
It had been recognized in 1944 that the new system could only commence after a return to normality following the disruption of World War II. It was expected that after a brief transition period of no more than five years, the international economy would recover and the system would enter into operation.
To promote the growth of world trade and to finance the postwar reconstruction of Europe, the planners at Bretton Woods created another institution, the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (IBRD), which is one of five agencies that make up the World Bank Group and is perhaps now the most important agency [of the World Bank Group]. The IBRD had an authorized capitalization of $10 billion and was expected to make loans of its own funds to underwrite private loans and to issue securities to raise new funds to make possible a speedy postwar recovery. The IBRD was to be a specialized agency of the United Nations charged with making loans for economic development purposes.

Readjustment[edit]

Dollar shortages and the Marshall Plan[edit]

The Bretton Woods arrangements were largely adhered to and ratified by the participating governments. It was expected that national monetary reserves, supplemented with necessary IMF credits, would finance any temporary balance of payments disequilibria. But this did not prove sufficient to get Europe out of its conundrum.
Postwar world capitalism suffered from a huge dollar shortage. The United States was running huge balance of trade surpluses, and the U.S. reserves were immense and growing. It was necessary to reverse this flow. Even though all nations wanted to buy US exports, dollars had to leave the United States and become available for international use in order for them to do so. In other words, the United States would have to reverse the imbalances in global wealth by running a balance of trade deficit, financed by an outflow of US reserves to other nations (a US financial account deficit). The US could run a financial deficit by either importing from, building plants in, or donating to foreign nations. Recall that speculative investment was discouraged by the Bretton Woods agreement. Importing from other nations was not appealing in the 1950s, because US technology was cutting edge at the time. So multinationals and global aid which originated from the US burgeoned.[25]
The modest credit facilities of the IMF were clearly insufficient to deal with Western Europe's huge balance of payments deficits. The problem was further aggravated by the reaffirmation by the IMF Board of Governors in the provision in the Bretton Woods Articles of Agreement that the IMF could make loans only for current account deficits and not for capital and reconstruction purposes. Only the United States contribution of $570 million was actually available for IBRD lending. In addition, because the only available market for IBRD bonds was the conservative Wall Street banking market, the IBRD was forced to adopt a conservative lending policy, granting loans only when repayment was assured. Given these problems, by 1947 the IMF and the IBRD themselves were admitting that they could not deal with the international monetary system's economic problems.[26]
The United States set up the European Recovery Program (Marshall Plan) to provide large-scale financial and economic aid for rebuilding Europe largely through grants rather than loans. This included countries belonging to the Soviet bloc, e.g., Poland. In a speech at Harvard University on 5 June 1947, U.S. Secretary of State George Marshall stated:
The breakdown of the business structure of Europe during the war was complete. … Europe's requirements for the next three or four years of foreign food and other essential products … principally from the United States … are so much greater than her present ability to pay that she must have substantial help or face economic, social and political deterioration of a very grave character.
— [Notes 4]
From 1947 until 1958, the U.S. deliberately encouraged an outflow of dollars, and, from 1950 on, the United States ran a balance of payments deficit with the intent of providing liquidity for the international economy. Dollars flowed out through various U.S. aid programs: the Truman Doctrine entailing aid to the pro-U.S. Greek and Turkish regimes, which were struggling to suppress communist revolution, aid to various pro-U.S. regimes in the Third World, and most important, the Marshall Plan. From 1948 to 1954 the United States provided 16 Western European countries $17 billion in grants.
To encourage long-term adjustment, the United States promoted European and Japanese trade competitiveness. Policies for economic controls on the defeated former Axis countries were scrapped. Aid to Europe and Japan was designed to rebuild productivity and export capacity. In the long run it was expected that such European and Japanese recovery would benefit the United States by widening markets for U.S. exports, and providing locations for U.S. capital expansion.

Cold War[edit]

In 1945, Roosevelt and Churchill prepared the postwar era by negotiating with Joseph Stalin at Yalta about respective zones of influence; this same year Germany was divided into four occupation zones (Soviet, American, British, and French).
Roosevelt and Henry Morgenthau insisted that the Big Four (United States, United Kingdom, the Soviet Union, and China) participate in the Bretton Woods conference in 1944,[27] but their goal was frustrated when the Soviet Union would not join the IMF. In the past, the reasons why the Soviet Union chose not to subscribe to the articles by December 1945 have been the subject of speculation. But since the release of relevant Soviet archives, it is now clear that the Soviet calculation was based on the behavior of the parties that had actually expressed their assent to the Bretton Woods Agreements.[citation needed] The extended debates about ratification that had taken place both in the UK and the U.S. were read in Moscow as evidence of the quick disintegration of the wartime alliance.[citation needed]
Facing the Soviet Union, whose power had also strengthened and whose territorial influence had expanded, the U.S. assumed the role of leader of the capitalist camp. The rise of the postwar U.S. as the world's leading industrial, monetary, and military power was rooted in the fact that the mainland U.S. was untouched by the war, in the instability of the national states in postwar Europe, and the wartime devastation of the Soviet and European economies.
Despite the economic effort imposed by such a policy, being at the center of the international market gave the U.S. unprecedented freedom of action in pursuing its foreign affairs goals. A trade surplus made it easier to keep armies abroad and to invest outside the U.S., and because other nations could not sustain foreign deployments, the U.S. had the power to decide why, when and how to intervene in global crises. The dollar continued to function as a compass to guide the health of the world economy, and exporting to the U.S. became the primary economic goal of developing or redeveloping economies. This arrangement came to be referred to as the Pax Americana, in analogy to the Pax Britannica of the late 19th century and the Pax Romana of the first. (See Globalism)

Late application[edit]

U.S. balance of payments crisis[edit]

After the end of World War II, the U.S. held $26 billion in gold reserves, of an estimated total of $40 billion (approx 65%). As world trade increased rapidly through the 1950s, the size of the gold base increased by only a few percentage points. In 1950, the U.S. balance of payments swung negative. The first U.S. response to the crisis was in the late 1950s when the Eisenhower administration placed import quotas on oil and other restrictions on trade outflows. More drastic measures were proposed, but not acted upon. However, with a mounting recession that began in 1958, this response alone was not sustainable. In 1960, with Kennedy's election, a decade-long effort to maintain the Bretton Woods System at the $35/ounce price was begun.
The design of the Bretton Woods System was that nations could only enforce gold convertibility on the anchor currency—the United States' dollar. Gold convertibility enforcement was not required, but instead, allowed. Nations could forgo converting dollars to gold, and instead hold dollars. Rather than full convertibility, it provided a fixed price for sales between central banks. However, there was still an open gold market. For the Bretton Woods system to remain workable, it would either have to alter the peg of the dollar to gold, or it would have to maintain the free market price for gold near the $35 per ounce official price. The greater the gap between free market gold prices and central bank gold prices, the greater the temptation to deal with internal economic issues by buying gold at the Bretton Woods price and selling it on the open market.
In 1960 Robert Triffin, Belgian American economist, noticed that holding dollars was more valuable than gold because constant U.S. balance of paymentsdeficits helped to keep the system liquid and fuel economic growth. What would later come to be known as Triffin's Dilemma was predicted when Triffin noted that if the U.S. failed to keep running deficits the system would lose its liquidity, not be able to keep up with the world's economic growth, and, thus, bring the system to a halt. But incurring such payment deficits also meant that, over time, the deficits would erode confidence in the dollar as the reserve currency created instability.[28]
The first effort was the creation of the London Gold Pool on 1 November 1961 between eight nations. The theory behind the pool was that spikes in the free market price of gold, set by the morning gold fix in London, could be controlled by having a pool of gold to sell on the open market, that would then be recovered when the price of gold dropped. Gold's price spiked in response to events such as the Cuban Missile Crisis, and other smaller events, to as high as $40/ounce. The Kennedy administration drafted a radical change of the tax system to spur more production capacity and thus encourage exports. This culminated with the 1963 tax cut program, designed to maintain the $35 peg.
In 1967, there was an attack on the pound and a run on gold in the sterling area, and on 18 November 1967, the British government was forced to devalue the pound.[29] U.S. President Lyndon Baines Johnson was faced with a brutal choice, either institute protectionist measures, including travel taxes, export subsidies and slashing the budget—or accept the risk of a "run on gold" and the dollar. From Johnson's perspective: "The world supply of gold is insufficient to make the present system workable—particularly as the use of the dollar as a reserve currency is essential to create the required international liquidity to sustain world trade and growth."[30]
He believed that the priorities of the United States were correct, and, although there were internal tensions in the Western alliance, that turning away from open trade would be more costly, economically and politically, than it was worth: "Our role of world leadership in a political and military sense is the only reason for our current embarrassment in an economic sense on the one hand and on the other the correction of the economic embarrassment under present monetary systems will result in an untenable position economically for our allies."[citation needed]
While West Germany agreed not to purchase gold from the U.S., and agreed to hold dollars instead, the pressure on both the dollar and the pound sterling continued. In January 1968 Johnson imposed a series of measures designed to end gold outflow, and to increase U.S. exports. This was unsuccessful, however, as in mid-March 1968 a dollar run on gold ensued through the free market in London, the London Gold Pool was dissolved first by the institution ofad hoc UK bank holidays at the request of the US government. This was followed by a full closure of the London gold market, also at the request of the US government, until a series of meetings were held that attempted to rescue or reform the existing system.[31]
All attempts to maintain the peg collapsed in November 1968, and a new policy program attempted to convert the Bretton Woods system into an enforcement mechanism of floating the gold peg, which would be set by either fiat policy or by a restriction to honor foreign accounts. The collapse of the gold pool and the refusal of the pool members to trade gold with private entities—on 18 March, 1968 the Congress of the United States repealed the 25% requirement of gold backing of the dollar[32]—as well as the US pledge to suspend gold sales to governments that trade in the private markets,[33] led to the expansion of the private markets for international gold trade, in which the price of gold rose much higher than the official dollar price.[34][35] The US gold reserves continued to be depleted due to the actions of some nations, notably France,[35] who continued to build up their gold reserves.

Structural changes[edit]

Return to convertibility[edit]

In the 1960s and 1970s, important structural changes eventually led to the breakdown of international monetary management. One change was the development of a high level of monetary interdependence. The stage was set for monetary interdependence by the return to convertibility of the Western European currencies at the end of 1958 and of the Japanese yen in 1964. Convertibility facilitated the vast expansion of international financial transactions, which deepened monetary interdependence.

Growth of international currency markets[edit]

Another aspect of the internationalization of banking has been the emergence of international banking consortia. Since 1964 various banks had formed international syndicates, and by 1971 over three quarters of the world's largest banks had become shareholders in such syndicates. Multinational banks can and do make huge international transfers of capital not only for investment purposes but also for hedging and speculating against exchange rate fluctuations.
These new forms of monetary interdependence made possible huge capital flows. During the Bretton Woods era, countries were reluctant to alter exchange rates formally even in cases of structural disequilibria. Because such changes had a direct impact on certain domestic economic groups, they came to be seen as political risks for leaders. As a result, official exchange rates often became unrealistic in market terms, providing a virtually risk-free temptation for speculators. They could move from a weak to a strong currency hoping to reap profits when a revaluation occurred. If, however, monetary authorities managed to avoid revaluation, they could return to other currencies with no loss. The combination of risk-free speculation with the availability of huge sums was highly destabilizing.

Decline[edit]

U.S. monetary influence[edit]
A second structural change that undermined monetary management was the decline of U.S. hegemony. The U.S. was no longer the dominant economic power it had been for more than two decades. By the mid-1960s, the E.E.C. and Japan had become international economic powers in their own right. With total reserves exceeding those of the U.S., higher levels of growth and trade, and per capita income approaching that of the U.S., Europe and Japan were narrowing the gap between themselves and the United States.
The shift toward a more pluralistic distribution of economic power led to increasing dissatisfaction with the privileged role of the U.S. dollar as the international currency. As in effect the world's central banker, the U.S., through its deficit, determined the level of international liquidity. In an increasingly interdependent world, U.S. policy greatly influenced economic conditions in Europe and Japan. In addition, as long as other countries were willing to hold dollars, the U.S. could carry out massive foreign expenditures for political purposes—military activities and foreign aid—without the threat of balance-of-payments constraints.
Dissatisfaction with the political implications of the dollar system was increased by détente between the U.S. and the Soviet Union. The Soviet threat had been an important force in cementing the Western capitalist monetary system. The U.S. political and security umbrella helped make American economic domination palatable for Europe and Japan, which had been economically exhausted by the war. As gross domestic production grew in European countries, trade grew. When common security tensions lessened, this loosened the transatlantic dependence on defence concerns, and allowed latent economic tensions to surface.
Dollar[edit]
Reinforcing the relative decline in U.S. power and the dissatisfaction of Europe and Japan with the system was the continuing decline of the dollar—the foundation that had underpinned the post-1945 global trading system. The Vietnam War and the refusal of the administration of U.S. President Lyndon B. Johnson to pay for it and its Great Society programs through taxation resulted in an increased dollar outflow to pay for the military expenditures and rampant inflation, which led to the deterioration of the U.S. balance of trade position.[citation needed] In the late 1960s, the dollar was overvalued with its current trading position, while the German Mark and the yen were undervalued; and, naturally, the Germans and the Japanese had no desire to revalue and thereby make their exports more expensive, whereas the U.S. sought to maintain its international credibility by avoiding devaluation.[36] Meanwhile, the pressure on government reserves was intensified by the new international currency markets, with their vast pools of speculative capital moving around in search of quick profits.[35]
In contrast, upon the creation of Bretton Woods, with the U.S. producing half of the world's manufactured goods and holding half its reserves, the twin burdens of international management and the Cold War were possible to meet at first. Throughout the 1950s Washington sustained a balance of payments deficit to finance loans, aid, and troops for allied regimes. But during the 1960s the costs of doing so became less tolerable. By 1970 the U.S. held under 16% of international reserves. Adjustment to these changed realities was impeded by the U.S. commitment to fixed exchange rates and by the U.S. obligation to convert dollars into gold on demand.[citation needed]

Paralysis of international monetary management[edit]

Floating-rate system during 1968–1972[edit]


The intent of the SDR system was to prevent nations from buying pegged gold and selling it at the higher free market price, and give nations a reason to hold dollars by crediting interest, at the same time setting a clear limit to the amount of dollars that could be held.
By 1968, the attempt to defend the dollar at a fixed peg of $35/ounce, the policy of the Eisenhower, Kennedy and Johnson administrations, had become increasingly untenable. Gold outflows from the U.S. accelerated, and despite gaining assurances from Germany and other nations to hold gold, the unbalanced fiscal spending of the Johnson administration had transformed the dollar shortage of the 1940s and 1950s into a dollar glut by the 1960s. In 1967, the IMF agreed in Rio de Janeiro to replace the tranche division set up in 1946. Special drawing rights (SDRs) were set as equal to one U.S. dollar, but were not usable for transactions other than between banks and the IMF. Nations were required to accept holding SDRs equal to three times their allotment, and interest would be charged, or credited, to each nation based on their SDR holding. The original interest rate was 1.5%.

Nixon Shock[edit]

Main article: Nixon Shock
A negative balance of payments, growing public debt incurred by the Vietnam War and Great Society programs, and monetary inflation by the Federal Reserve caused the dollar to become increasingly overvalued.[37] The drain on US gold reserves culminated with the London Gold Pool collapse in March 1968.[38] By 1970, the U.S. had seen its gold coverage deteriorate from 55% to 22%. This, in the view of neoclassical economists, represented the point where holders of the dollar had lost faith in the ability of the U.S. to cut budget and trade deficits.
In 1971 more and more dollars were being printed in Washington, then being pumped overseas, to pay for government expenditure on the military and social programs. In the first six months of 1971, assets for $22 billion fled the U.S. In response, on 15 August 1971, Nixon issued Executive Order 11615 pursuant to the Economic Stabilization Act of 1970, unilaterally imposing 90-day wage and price controls, a 10% import surcharge, and most importantly "closed the gold window", making the dollar inconvertible to gold directly, except on the open market. Unusually, this decision was made without consulting members of the international monetary system or even his own State Department, and was soon dubbed the Nixon Shock.

Smithsonian Agreement[edit]

The August shock was followed by efforts under U.S. leadership to reform the international monetary system. Throughout the fall of 1971, a series of multilateral and bilateral negotiations between the Group of Ten countries took place, seeking to redesign the exchange rate regime.
Meeting in December 1971 at the Smithsonian Institution in Washington D.C., the Group of Ten signed the Smithsonian Agreement. The US pledged to peg the dollar at $38/ounce with 2.25% trading bands, and other countries agreed to appreciate their currencies versus the dollar. The group also planned to balance the world financial system using special drawing rights alone.
The agreement failed to encourage discipline by the Federal Reserve or the United States government. The Federal Reserve was concerned about an increase in the domestic unemployment rate due to the devaluation of the dollar. In attempt to undermine the efforts of the Smithsonian Agreement, the Federal Reserve lowered interest rates in pursuit of a previously established domestic policy objective of full national employment. With the Smithsonian Agreement, member countries anticipated return flow of dollars to the U.S, but the reduced interest rates within the United States caused dollars to continue to flow out of the U.S. and into foreign central banks. The inflow of dollars into foreign banks continued the monetization process of the dollar overseas, defeating the aims of the Smithsonian Agreement. As a result, the dollar price in the gold free market continued to cause pressure on its official rate; soon after a 10% devaluation was announced in February 1973, Japan and the EEC countries decided to let their currencies float. This proved to be the beginning of the collapse of the Bretton Woods System. A decade later, all industrialized nations had done so.[39][40]

Bretton Woods II[edit]

Main article: Bretton Woods II
Dooley, Folkerts-Landau and Garber have referred to the monetary system of today as Bretton Woods II.[41] They argue that in the early 2000s (decade) the international system is composed of a core issuing the dominant international currency, and a periphery. The periphery is committed to export-led growthbased on the maintenance of an undervalued exchange rate. In the 1960s, the core was the United States and the periphery was Europe and Japan. This old periphery has since graduated, and the new periphery is Asia. The core remains the same, the United States. The argument is that a system of pegged currencies—in which the periphery exports capital to the core, which serves an intermediary financial role—is both stable and desirable, although this notion is controversial.[41]
Sanjeev Sanyal, a colleague to Garber, Dooley and Folkerts-Landau, has taken this framework further to argue that mainstream economists are wrong to insist on global balance. He argues that disequilibrium is the natural state of the world and that all periods of economic expansion were underpinned by symbiotic imbalances. Such imbalances cause distortions, but economists should focus on mitigating the distortions rather than on wishing away the imbalances. Thus, he feel that the next round of economic expansion will witness a return to imbalances that he dubs Bretton Woods III.[42][43]

The Bretton Woods system after the 2008 crisis[edit]

In the wake of the Global financial crisis of 2008, policymakers and others have called for a new international monetary system that some of them also dubBretton Woods II. On the other side, this crisis has revived the debate about Bretton Woods II.[Notes 5]
On 26 September 2008, French President Nicolas Sarkozy said, "we must rethink the financial system from scratch, as at Bretton Woods."[44]
On 24–25 September 2009 US President Obama hosted the G20 in Pittsburgh. A realignment of currency exchange rates was proposed. This meeting's policy outcome could be known as the Pittsburgh Agreement of 2009, where deficit nations may devalue their currencies and surplus nations may revalue theirs upward.
In March 2010, Prime Minister Papandreou of Greece wrote an op-ed in the International Herald Tribune, in which he said, "Democratic governments worldwide must establish a new global financial architecture, as bold in its own way as Bretton Woods, as bold as the creation of the European Community and European Monetary Union. And we need it fast." In interviews coinciding with his meeting with President Obama, he indicated that Obama would raise the issue of new regulations for the international financial markets at the next G20 meetings in June and November 2010.
Over the course of the crisis, the IMF progressively relaxed its stance on "free-market" principles such as its guidance against using capital controls. In 2011, the IMF's managing director Dominique Strauss-Kahn stated that boosting employment and equity "must be placed at the heart" of the IMF's policy agenda.[45] The World Bank indicated a switch towards greater emphases on job creation.[46][47]
However, Deutsche Bank's Sanjeev Sanyal has argued that the insistence on global balance is fundamentally flawed and that sustained economic growth has always relied on symbiotic imbalances. This means that the world will eventually have to accept a return to new period of imbalance that he calls Bretton Woods III.[42]

Pegged rates[edit]

Dates shown are those on which the rate was introduced; "*" indicates floating rate supplied by IMF[48]

Japanese yen[edit]

Date# yen = $1 US
August 194615
12 March 194750
5 July 1948270
25 April 1949360
20 July 1971308
30 December 1998115.60*
5 December 200892.499*
19 March 201180.199*
3 August 201177.250*
Note: GDP for 2012 is $4.525 trillion US Dollars[49]

German Mark[edit]

Date# Mark = $1 USNote
21 June 19483.33Eur 1.7026
18 September 19494.20Eur 2.1474
6 March 19614Eur 2.0452
29 October 19693.67Eur 1.8764
30 December 19981.673*Last day of trading; converted to Euro (4 January 1999)
Note: GDP for 2012 is $3.123 trillion US Dollars[49]

Pound sterling[edit]

Date# pounds = $1 US
27 December 19450.2481
18 September 19490.3571
17 November 19670.4167
30 December 19980.598*
5 December 20080.681*
Note: GDP for 2012 is $2.323 trillion US Dollars[49]

French franc[edit]

Date# francs = $1 USNote
27 December 19451.1911£1 = 4.8 FRF
26 January 19482.1439£1 = 8.64 FRF
18 October 19482.6352£1 = 10.62 FRF
27 April 19492.7221£1 = 10.97 FRF
20 September 19493.5£1 = 9.8 FRF
11 August 19574.2£1 = 11.76 FRF
27 December 19584.93711 FRF = 0.18  g gold
1 January 19604.93711 new franc = 100 old francs
10 August 19695.551 new franc = 0.160 g gold
31 December 19985.627*Last day of trading; converted to euro (4 January 1999)
Note: GDP for 2012 is $2.253 trillion US Dollars[49]

Italian lira[edit]

Date# lire = $1 USNote
4 January 1946225Eur 0.1162
26 March 1946509Eur 0.2629
7 January 1947350Eur 0.1808
28 November 1947575Eur 0.297
18 September 1949625Eur 0.3228
31 December 19981,654.569*Last day of trading; converted to euro (4 January 1999)
Note: GDP for 2012 is $1.834 trillion US Dollars[49]

Spanish peseta[edit]

Date# pesetas = $1 USNote
17 July 195960Eur 0.3606
20 November 196770Devalued in line with sterling
31 December 1998142.734*Last day of trading; converted to euro (4 January 1999)
Note: GDP for 2012 is $1.409 trillion US Dollars[49]

Dutch guilder[edit]

Date# gulden = $1 USNote
27 December 19452.652Eur 1.2034
20 September 19493.8Eur 1.7244
7 March 19613.62Eur 1.6427
31 December 19981.888*Last day of trading; converted to euro (4 January 1999)
Note: GDP for 2012 is $709.5 billion US Dollars[49]

Belgian franc[edit]

Date# francs = $1 USNote
27 December 194543.77Eur 1.085
194643.8725Eur 1.0876
21 September 194950Eur 1.2395
31 December 199834.605*Last day of trading; converted to euro (4 January 1999)
Note: GDP for 2012 is $419.6 billion US Dollars[49]

Swiss franc[edit]

Date# francs = $1 USNote
27 December 19454.30521£1 = 17.35 CHF
September 19494.375£1 = 12.25 CHF
31 December 19981.377*£1 = 2.289 CHF
5 December 20081.211*£1 = 1.778 CHF
15 January 2015Peg droppedPeg dropped amidst ECB 1 trillion euro Quantitative Easing devaluation.
Note: GDP for 2012 is $362.4 billion US Dollars[49]

Greek drachma[edit]

Date# drachmae = $1 USNote
195430Eur 0.088
31 December 2000281.821*Last day of trading; converted to euro (2001)
Note: GDP for 2012 is $280.8 billion US Dollars[49]

Danish krone[edit]

Date# kroner = $1 USNote
August 19454.8
19 September 19496.91Devalued in line with sterling
21 November 19677.5
31 December 19986.392*
5 December 20085.882*
Note: GDP for 2012 is $208.5 billion US Dollars[49]

Finnish markka[edit]

Date# markka = $1 USNote
17 October 19451.36Eur 0.2287
5 July 19491.6Eur 0.2691
19 September 19492.3Eur 0.3868
15 September 19573.2Eur 0.5382
1 January 19633.21 new markka = 100 old markka
12 October 19674.2Eur 0.7064. Pegged to a basket in 1971, floated in 1991
30 December 19985.084*Last day of trading; converted to euro (4 January 1999)
Note: GDP for 2012 is $198.1 billion US Dollars[49]

Norwegian krone[edit]

Date# kroner = $1 USNote
15 September 19464.03Joined Bretton Woods. £1 = 20.00 krone[50]
19 September 19497.15Devalued in line with sterling[51]
15 August 19717.016*Bretton Woods collapsed
21 December 19716.745Joined the Smithsonian Treaty
23 May 19726.571Joined the "European Currency Snake"
16 November 19726.611*The Smithsonian Treaty collapsed
12 December 19785.096*Left "the snake", linked to a "basket" of currencies
October 19905.920*Pegged to the ECU
12 December 19926.684*Fully floating
Note: GDP for 2014 is $339.5 billion US Dollars[49]

See also[edit]

General:

Notes[edit]

  1. Jump up^ For discussions of how liberal ideas motivated U.S. foreign economic policy after World War II, see, e.g., Kenneth WaltzMan, the State and War (New YorkColumbia University Press, 1969) and yuvi.c Calleo and Benjamin M. Rowland, American and World Political Economy (Bloomington, IndianaIndiana University Press, 1973).
  2. Jump up^ Quoted in Robert A. Pollard, Economic Security and the Origins of the Cold War, 1945–1950 (New York: Columbia University Press, 1985), p.8.
  3. Jump up^ Comments by John Maynard Keynes in his speech at the closing plenary session of the Bretton Woods Conference on July 22, 1944 in Donald Moggeridge (ed.), The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes (London: Cambridge University Press, 1980), vol. 26, p. 101. This comment also can be found quoted online at [1]
  4. Jump up^ Comments by U.S. Secretary of State George Marshall in his June 1947 speech "Against Hunger, Poverty, Desperation and Chaos" at a Harvard University commencement ceremony. A full transcript of his speech can be read online at [2]
  5. Jump up^ For a recent publication see Dooley, M.; Folkerts-Landau, D.; Garber, P. (2009). "Bretton Woods Ii Still Defines the International Monetary System". Pacific Economic Review 14 (3): 297–311. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0106.2009.00453.x.

Brettonwoodský systém

Hotel Mount Washington, v němž se konference konala
Harry Dexter White a John Maynard Keynes na Brettonwoodské konferenci
Brettonwoodský (měnový) systém byl systém regulace mezinárodních měnových vztahů založený na režimu pevných směnných kurzů. Vyžadoval od každé členské země, aby udržovala fluktuaci svých směnných kurzů v rozpětí jednoho procenta kolem pari hodnoty vyjádřené v amerických dolarech.[1] Pojmenován je podle okresu Bretton Woods v New HampshireUSA, kde byl systém v roce 1944 dohodnut. Trval od roku 1945 do srpna 1971.

Před konferencí v Bretton Woods[editovat | editovat zdroj]

Podrobnější informace naleznete v článku Zlatý standard.
Až do začátku první světové války byla hodnota jednotlivých měn navázána na zlato (například americký dolar byl definován jako 1/20 unce zlata), a toto navázání znemožňovalo vydávat nové ničím nekryté peníze.[2] Enormní válečné výdaje vedly válčící strany k opuštění zlata a inflaci,[3] protože inflace je svého druhu zdanění, na rozdíl od skutečných daní však jej není třeba veřejně vyhlašovat a lze jej provádět i bez vědomého souhlasu veřejnosti.[4]Všechny významné měny se tak znehodnocovaly, dolar o něco méně, neboť Spojené státy vstoupily do války později.[3] Po skončení první světové války se už ani jedna ze stran k původnímu standardu nevrátila.[3]

Brettonwoodská dohoda[editovat | editovat zdroj]

V červenci 1944 se v hotelu Mount Washington v okresu Bretton Woods v New HampshireUSA konala jednání mezi 44 zeměmi (v nichž měly hlavní slovoVelká Británie a Spojené státy americké) o nové koncepci peněžního systému, která by v poválečném světě mohla být zavedena. Výsledkem byla tzv. brettonwoodská dohoda (též opisně nazývaná standard ekvivalence dolaru a zlata) coby první globální peněžní konstituce. Body této konference se promýšlely dva roky dopředu. Podstatou dohody bylo napojení amerického dolaru na zlato a všech ostatních měn na dolar. Dolar sám byl fixován jako 1/35unce zlata.[5] Směňovat dolary za zlato ovšem směly pouze vlády, nikolv občané. Dohoda byla podepsána všemi 45 zúčastněnými zeměmi a v následujícím roce, 1945, vstoupila v platnost.
Jako zástupci Československa byli jednání přítomni Ladislav FeierabendJan Viktor MládekAntonín BaschErvin Exner a Josef Hanč.

Důsledky Brettonwoodské dohody[editovat | editovat zdroj]

Americký dolar získal status oficiální celosvětové rezervní měny, od které navíc budou měny ostatních zemí odvozeny. Současně Spojené státy musely garantovat směnitelnost dolaru za zlato v pevně stanoveném kurzu 35 dolarů za trojskou unci zlata (jednalo se o jistou formu zlatého standardu).[5] V zájmu centrálních bank ostatních států bylo vytvořit si dostatečné měnové rezervy právě v amerických dolarech. To zpětně zvýšilo atraktivitu této měny a posílilo její postavení v poválečném světě.

Organizace vzešlé z Brettonwoodské dohody[editovat | editovat zdroj]

Brettonwoodská dohoda dala vzniknout Stabilizačnímu fondu, později Mezinárodnímu měnovému fondu, který nad nově vzniklým systémem začal dohlížet. Dále pak vznikla Mezinárodní banka pro obnovu a rozvoj, později Světová banka (World Bank, WB). Naopak, bylo navrženo zrušení Banky pro mezinárodní vypořádání (the Bank of International Settlements) za flagrantní spolupráci s nacistickým režimem, ale tento krok nakonec na konferenci neprošel (i vzhledem k nutnosti formy předpokládaných poválečných reparací Německa).

Uzavření zlatého okna[editovat | editovat zdroj]

Vývoj ceny zlata v amerických dolarech. Prudký vzestup nominální hodnoty se časově shoduje s uzavřením zlatého okna
Konverze dolaru za zlato nebyla vymahatelná jednotlivcem, ale měly na ni nárok centrální banky jiných zemí.[5] V důsledku to znamenalo, že centrální banka Spojených států (Federální rezervní systém) byla povinna na žádost bank jiných zemí směnit dodanou sumu dolarů za odpovídající množství zlata.[5] Vlády Spojených států však postupně produkovaly více papírových peněz, než by odpovídalo tomuto kurzu.[5] Ostatní země, zvláště Francie, na to reagovaly požadavky na směnu dolarů za zlato, což vedlo k odčerpávání zlata drženého americkými bankami z území Spojených států a USA o své měnové zlato přicházely.[5] Vzhledem k tomu, že Spojené státy americké měly po druhé světové válce značné zásoby zlata, se držel systém poměrně dlouho, ale koncem 60. let (zejména po programu „zbraní a másla“ prezidenta Lyndona Johnsona) se začal rozpadat.[5]
Spojené státy na to v březnu 1968 reagovaly úpravou, podle které mělo být americké měnové zlato obchodováno zcela odděleně (stále za cenu 35 dolarů za unci) od zlata na světových trzích. Ostatní vlády se zavázaly neprodávat ani nenakupovat toto zlato jinde.[6] V srpnu roku 1971, kdy o splnění závazku podle brettonwoodské dohody zažádalyFrancie a Velká Británie, jim tehdejší prezident Richard Nixon nevyhověl a 15. srpna tzv. uzavřením zlatého oknabrettonwoodský systém zrušil. To vedlo k éře pohyblivých devizových kurzů. Cena zlata během několika měsíců od konce Brettonwoodské dohody vzrostla řádově desetinásobně.
Nástupcem Brettonwoodského systému byla Smithsoniánská dohoda, podepsaná v prosinci 1971. Americký prezident Nixon ji nazval "Největší měnovou dohodou v dějinách lidstva".[2] Dohoda zafixovala kurzy mnohých evropských měn vůči dolaru (kurzy byly podhodnocené).[7] Spojené státy navíc devalvovaly oficiální kurz dolaru na 1/38 unce zlata.[7] Pokračující inflace v USA ale vedla k tomu, že bylo stále obtížnější udržet stávající nadhodnocený kurz dolaru, a již v březnu 1973 se smithsoniánský systém zhroutil.[7]

Odkazy[editovat | editovat zdroj]

Reference[editovat | editovat zdroj]

  1. Skočit nahoru SLANÝ, Antonín; ŽÁK, Milan. Hospodářská politika. 1. vyd. Praha : C. H. Beck, 1999. ISBN 80-7179-237-3. Kapitola Stručný výkladový slovník, s. 259.
  2. ↑ Skočit nahoru k:a b ROTHBARD, MurrayPeníze v rukou státu. Praha : Liberální institut, 2001. 144 s. ISBN 80-86389-12-X. S. 88 - 90.
  3. ↑ Skočit nahoru k:a b c ROTHBARD, MurrayPeníze v rukou státu. Praha : Liberální institut, 2001. 144 s. ISBN 80-86389-12-X. S. 90 - 91.
  4. Skočit nahoru ROTHBARD, MurrayPeníze v rukou státu. Praha : Liberální institut, 2001. 144 s. ISBN 80-86389-12-X. S. 60 - 61.
  5. ↑ Skočit nahoru k:a b c d e f g ROTHBARD, MurrayPeníze v rukou státu. Praha : Liberální institut, 2001. 144 s. ISBN 80-86389-12-X. S. 95 - 97.
  6. Skočit nahoru ROTHBARD, MurrayPeníze v rukou státu. Praha : Liberální institut, 2001. 144 s. ISBN 80-86389-12-X. S. 98 - 99.
  7. ↑ Skočit nahoru k:a b c ROTHBARD, MurrayPeníze v rukou státu. Praha : Liberální institut, 2001. 144 s. ISBN 80-86389-12-X. S. 100 - 101.

Související články[editovat | editovat zdroj]

Externí odkazy[editovat | editovat zdroj]

  • Bernard Lietaer: Budoucnost peněz, paradigma.sk, ISBN 80-968603-3-X, str 286 a 296
  • NOVOTNÝ, Radovan. Je všemohoucí americký dolar odsouzen k zániku?. Měšec.cz [online]. , 9. 6 2009 [cit. 2012-10-21]. Dostupné online.
  • NOVOTNÝ, Radovan. Jak vznikl systém volně směnitelných kurzů?. Investujeme.cz [online]. , 23. 9 2008 [cit. 2012-10-21]. Dostupné online.

No comments:

Post a Comment